Friday 1 May 2015

Rare dissent as the Competition Appeal Tribunal upholds the CMA’s private health care remedy


The Competition Appeal Tribunal (CAT) has dismissed an appeal by the Federation of Independent Practitioner Organisations (FIPO) against the CMA’s final report and remedies in its market investigation into private healthcare.  The CAT reached its judgment by a majority, in the face of a powerful dissenting opinion by Dermot Glynn, the panel’s economist.  What is interesting in this outcome is the vigour with which the dissenting opinion was expressed.  There have been only three previous dissents in challenges before the CAT, yet the issue in those cases was relatively self-contained relating to judicial review against Ofcom.  Here, the economist member concludes that the CMA’s decision was irrational. 

The CMA concluded in its final report that competition between private doctors is not prevented or restricted by any market power exerted by private medical insurers (PMIs).  Rather, it considered that adverse effects on competition (AEC) arose from the lack of public information on doctors’ fees.  It therefore considered that the appropriate remedy was an order to consultants to publish information on their fees and performance. 

FIPO challenged the CMA’s findings on a number of grounds, all of which were dismissed by the CAT.  The majority also considered that the view expressed in the dissenting opinion was based on an incorrect interpretation of the scope of judicial review where a review of the merits of the underlying decision is forbidden territory. 

The dissenting opinion makes interesting reading.  Glynn concluded that it was irrational for the CMA to find that fee-capping and limits on top-up fees did not necessarily restrict patients’ choice and constitute an AEC.  He commented that the CMA did not consider two aspects of consumer choice, namely where a majority of PMI patients are: (a) unlikely to have a choice between a consultant recommended by the PMI and another offering better service but requiring a top-up fee, and (b) unlikely to have a choice between different levels of service offered by the same consultant.  Rather, the CMA seems to have based its conclusion on its finding that there was no change in the aggregate number of consultants; hence no AEC as regards consumer choice.  However, Glynn took the view that the number of consultants is not necessarily correlated with the degree of patient choice in the market in terms of different pricing propositions and quality. 

Glynn could see no competition law or other justification for effectively preventing top-up fees being sought by many individual consultants whose expertise or popularity would allow this, and whose patients would be willing to pay.   He considered, also, that the mere possibility of competition below the cap ignores the operation of the market in practice:  ‘The absence of competition on price is in my opinion inescapably an AEC by comparison with a normally competitive market […] For the CMA to find no AEC on the ground that consultants “could” compete below the fee caps did not have regard to the economic realities, and was therefore irrational’ (para 87, Judgment). 

Glynn considered that the remedy was not effective because providing more information on fees does not address the lack of competition on fees:  ‘There is only limited competition through top-up fees. There is thus no real price competition between consultants so far as policyholders are concerned. On that basis, providing information about fees to policyholders will do nothing to improve the competitive outcome because there is no competition on those fees in the first place. Providing information about distorted fees cannot be expected to improve the competitive outcome’ (para 96, Judgment). 

The CAT’s judgment may be appealed to the Court of Appeal on a point of law.  

Federation of Independent Practitioner Organisations v CMA [2015] CAT 8, 29 April 2015

No comments:

Post a Comment